Categories
Elham's Money View Blog

Is Libra Money? Depends on Where in Credit Cycle We Are

By Elham Saeidinezhad

“What institutions build, they can destroy.” Anonymous

Mark Zuckerberg’s testimony to Congress on October 24th, 2019, created anxieties on whether Facebook would circumvent financial regulators as it readies its planned cryptocurrency, Libra. This concern by policymakers was logical, given the magnitude of the 2008-09 global financial crisis and its effects on the international monetary system. The company’s promise to move forward with Libra only when they had explicit approval from all U.S. financial regulators seem to calm some of those fears. However, a more fundamental enigma at the heart of Libra is a classical puzzle in monetary economics of what is the nature of “money” and its relationship with the payment system. When examining Libra, we have too often overlooked the fact that although the medium of exchange and the means of payments coincide with each other when the financial condition is stable, they are not the same. In doing so, we have lost some valuable insights into Libra’s state during a financial crisis.

To shed some light on this mystery, let’s start by focusing on the technical definition of the monetary system, which is money plus the settlement mechanisms to execute payments. In mainstream economic literature, the focus is totally on money and its role as a “medium of exchange.” Therefore, as long as people “trust” Libra and use it to purchase goods and services, the monetary system should work seamlessly. During economic and credit expansion, when the financial market is elastic, mainstream interpretation of the monetary system seems to work. The problem is that during the financial crisis, guaranteeing this trust is a complicated task. Under these circumstances, the precondition for a well-functioning monetary system is the trust that payments will be executed, and the object functioning as a medium of exchange is convertible to the means of final payments.

This condition has substantial implications for the position of Libra in the future financial crisis.  On the one hand, alongside regulatory agencies, central banks’ role in backstopping the payment system becomes critical in securing convertibility and trust. On the other hand, Libra is a decentralized currency that is issued by private entities. Therefore, when confidence evaporates in the financial market, it is very likely that Libra cannot be converted to the means of final payments unless it receives a public bailout. The hiccup is that in the process of understanding Libra as a form of money, we have too often ignored the more intangible aspect of the monetary system- the payment system. The danger is that the public will pay the bill.

Discussion Questions:

  1. In your opinion, why do standard economic theories tend to overlook payment systems in their models?
  2. What is the prerequisite for Libra to continue its function as a currency when a severe financial crisis hit the economy?
Categories
Elham's Money View Blog

Quantitative Easing: No Words to Describe It

By Elham Saeidinezhad

“Words have no power to impress the mind without the exquisite horror of their reality.” – Edgar Allan Poe

The experience of the global financial crisis (GFC) was a painful reminder that central banks were not equipped to save the modern financial markets from failing. To this end, the Fed reimagined its role by employing “unconventional tools” to restore market liquidity and stopping the freefall. While the Fed used to flush the banking system with liquidity in earlier crises, it was engaged in the outright purchases of long-term government bonds and mortgage-backed securities (MBS) during the GFC. This procedure was later known as ‘’Quantitative Easing” or QE. Similarly, to respond to the most recent turbulences in the repo market, the Fed has started the same kind of operations by purchasing short-dated government bills from September. The difference, however, is their resistance to label this procedure as a QE.

The experience of the global financial crisis (GFC) was a painful reminder that central banks were not equipped to save the modern financial markets from failing. To this end, the Fed reimagined its role by employing “unconventional tools” to restore market liquidity and stopping the freefall. While the Fed used to flush the banking system with liquidity in earlier crises, it was engaged in the outright purchases of long-term government bonds and mortgage-backed securities (MBS) during the GFC. This procedure was later known as ‘’Quantitative Easing” or QE. Similarly, to respond to the most recent turbulences in the repo market, the Fed has started the same kind of operations by purchasing short-dated government bills from September. The difference, however, is their resistance to label this procedure as a QE.

Regardless of whether or not to call it a QE, the seismic shift in the Fed’s role away from being a lender of last resort to the banks towards the dealer of last resort in the capital market continues a decade after the GFC. This new role of the Fed reflects the evolving nature of the financial market where liquidity provision has shifted from the business model of the large banks to nonbanks. These nonbanks, who are collectively known as ‘’shadow banking system,” are mostly dealers who are financing their long term investments in the capital market by borrowing in the wholesale money market using short term instruments such as repo.

Capturing this evolution is a welcome development in the world of central banking. The point is that QE is a new normal way of executing monetary policy and is better-adjusted to deal with fluctuations in the financial system. Against this background, it seems like we have to start calling the asset-purchasing program of the Fed what it is: a permanent tool of implementing monetary policy. This task of reimaging central banking has been long overdue, and QE is a first step in the right direction. Besides, it is here to stay.

Discussion Questions:

1. What is the main difference between the Fed’s QE and the new round of asset purchasing program?

2. Do you think the Fed should react to liquidity problems outside the traditional banking system?

3. Do you think the growth of the shadow banking system in the financial market should be curbed using financial regulations?

Categories
About Me

Elham Saeidinezhad, Ph.D.

About Me

I am a Term Assistant Professor of Economics at Barnard College, Columbia University, where I teach courses on finance, monetary systems, and economics. Additionally, I am an instructor for “The Financial System” (modern Money and Banking) at the Economics Department of NYU Stern.

Beyond teaching, I lead the “Market Microstructure” Project, where I analyze research from major financial institutions, monitor shifts in financial market structures, and explore their implications for financial stability and the future of central banking. This project was previously affiliated with the Jain Family Institute. However, to ensure its integrity and maintain a focused, unbiased exploration of evolving market dynamics, the project has transitioned to an independent platform on Market Microstructure Substack. This transition allows for active engagement with academics, practitioners, and regulators.

In the realm of online education, I am an instructor for the Introduction to Macroeconomics course at Outlier, where I teach chapters on International Finance, Economics of Money and Credit, and Central Banking.

Before joining Barnard, I was a Lecturer of Economics at UCLA’s Economics Department, where I taught courses in Money and Banking, Macroeconomic Theory, and Monetary Economics, as well as supervised undergraduate research. My professional experience includes working as a research economist in the International Finance and Macroeconomics group at the Milken Institute in Santa Monica, where I studied post-crisis structural changes in capital markets driven by macroprudential regulations. Additionally, I served as a postdoctoral fellow at the Institute for New Economic Thinking (INET) in New York, collaborating closely with Prof. Perry Mehrling to study his “Money View” framework. This framework emphasizes liquidity and examines the realities of modern monetary systems using models of market microstructure.

I earned my Ph.D. in Empirical Macroeconomics in 2013 from the University of Sheffield.

Research

My research lies at the intersection of Market Microstructure, Industrial Organization, and Financial Economics, with a strong focus on financial stability and liquidity. I integrate theories from Market Microstructure and Industrial Organization, including their derivatives, such as the “Money View,” to address pressing topics in Financial Economics. 

This interdisciplinary approach bridges modern monetary and financial systems to explore critical questions about financial stability. By synthesizing these perspectives, I aim to enhance our understanding of how evolving market structures influence the resilience of financial systems.

Teaching Philosophy

Teaching is my greatest passion, and my students are an endless source of inspiration. I teach a variety of courses, including Accounting and Finance, Monetary Economics, Central Banking, Money and Banking, Financial Economics, Microeconomics, and Macroeconomics.

I am deeply committed to educating and engaging with my students, fostering an environment where ideas are debated and explored. I firmly believe that I have learned more from my students than from anyone else, and their enthusiasm continuously drives me to grow as an educator.

I can be reached via email <elham.saeidinezhad@gmail.com> , <esaeidin@barnard.edu>, <elham.saeidinezhad@stern.nyu.edu> , <elham.saeidinezhad@jfiresearch.org>, LinkedIn and Twitter<@elham_saeidi>