Categories
Elham's Money View Blog

Is Monetary Policy Divorcing from Money Market and Uniting with Capital Market?

By Elham Saeidinezhad

“The pronouncements and actions of the Federal Reserve Board on monetary policy are a charade.” Fischer Black

As the US Department of Treasury builds the points along the yield curve, the bank reserves are losing relevance in explaining short-term money market rates’ behavior. Central banks assume that they can create a close link between the best form of money (reserve) and monetary policy. They use the supply of reserves precisely to achieve the target interest rate. Since the 2008-09 Great Financial Crisis (GFC), however, the relationship between money and monetary policy has become unstable. After the COVID-19 pandemic, for instance, the Fed’s actions more than doubled the supply of bank reserves, from approximately $1.5 trillion in March to more than $3 trillion in June. In theory, such a massive increase in the supply of reserves should reduce the money market rates. Yet, short-term money market rates have been surprisingly steady, despite the enormous increase in reserves during the great lockdown. Fed economists recognize the over-supply of short-term US Treasury bills (a money market instrument) as the leading cause of the puzzling behavior in money market rates and call it “friction.” 

However, for the Money View scholars, dividing the money market from the capital market, assuming that prices in each market are solely determined by its supply and demand flow, has never been an effective way of understanding interest rates. In the Money View world, similar to Fischer Black’s CAPM, the arbitrage condition implies that both the quantity and the price of money are ultimately determined by private dealers borrowing and lending activities that connect different markets rather than the stance of monetary policy alone. Dealers engage in “yield spread arbitrage,” in which they identify apparent mispricing (i.e., temporary fluctuations in supply or demand) at one segment of the yield curve, and takes a position. Dealers take “positions,” which means they speculate on how prices of assets with similar risk structure but different term-to-maturity, will change. In the meantime, they hedge interest rate exposures by taking an opposite position at another segment of the yield curve.

The point to emphasize is that short-term money markets and long-term capital markets are, in fact, not separate. As a result, prices in each market are not solely determined by the flow of supply and demand in that particular market. By taking advantage of the arbitrage opportunity, the dealers act as “porters” of liquidity from one market to another and connect prices in different markets in the process. The instruments that allow the dealers to transfer liquidity and solidify markets are repos and reverse repos, where capital market assets are used as collaterals to borrow from the money market, or vice versa. The Money View’s strength in understanding price dynamics comes from its ability, and willingness, to understand the dealers whose business connects different points of the yield curve and determines the effectiveness of the monetary policy.

During the COVID-19 pandemic, two separate but equally essential developments (aka distortions) occurred along the yield curve. In the long-term capital market, the Treasury has introduced a new class of safe assets, a 20-year Treasury bond, with a high yield (corresponding to the lowest accepted bid price) of 1.22 percent. Effectively, the US Treasury added a new point to the long-term end of the yield curve. In the short-term money market, the Fed injected a massive amount of reserves to reduce money market rates. The standard view suggests that such an increase in the supply of reserves would reduce the money market rates. The idea is that banks are the only institutions that hold these extra reserves. Due to balance sheet constraints, such as banks’ regulatory requirements, higher reserve holding implies higher banks’ costs. Therefore, banks reduce their short-term rates to signal their willingness to lend. In practice, however, short-term rates remained unchanged.

This dynamic in money market rates can be explained by the recent developments in the Treasury market, a segment of the capital market, and actions of the dealers who took advantage of the consequent arbitrage opportunity along the yield curve, i.e., the high spread between the short-term money market and the long-term risk-free Treasury rates. The dealers increased demand in the short-term money market both for hedging, and financing the newly issued Treasury bonds, put upward pressure on short-term rates. In contrast, the Fed’s activities put downward pressure on these rates. Observe that an increase in private demand for short-term funding (due to yield spread arbitrage) and an increase in the supply of reserves by the Fed (due to monetary policy) have opposing effects on short-term rates. Thus, it should not be surprising that despite the excessive reserve supply after the pandemic, the money market rates have remained stable. Understanding this kind of arbitrage along the yield curve is essential in understanding the behavior of short-term rates and the monetary policy’s effectiveness.

What is missing in this literature, but emphasized in the Money View framework, is acknowledging the hybridity between the money market and the capital market. The close link between the US Treasury market and the money market is a feature of the shadow banking or the new market-based finance. It is no friction. More importantly, the dealers’ search for “arbitrage” opportunities implies that individual securities markets are not separate. Speculators are joining the different markets into a single market. In doing so, they bring about a result that is no part of their intention, namely liquidity. As the Treasury creates an additional risk-free, liquid, point along the yield curve, it creates more arbitrage opportunities. Such developments make the yield curve an even more critical tool of examining the monetary policy effects. In the meantime, the traditional framework of supply and demand for bank reserves to control the short-term money market rate is losing its pertinence.

Categories
Elham's Money View Blog Search For Stable Liquidity Providers Series

What Can Explain the Tale of Two FX Swap Rates in the Offshore Dollar Funding Market?

This Piece Is Part of the “Search For Stable Liquidity Providers” Series.

By Elham Saeidinezhad

Mary Stigum once said, “Don’t fight the Fed!” There is perhaps no better advice that someone can give to an investor than to heed these words.

After the COVID-19 crisis, most aspects of the dollar funding market have shown some bizarre developments. In particular, the LIBOR-OIS spread, which used to be the primary measure of the cost of dollar funding globally, is losing its relevance. This spread has been sidelined by the strong bond between the rivals, namely CP/CD ratio and the FX swap basis. The problem is that such a switch, if proved to be premature, could create uncertainty, rather than stability, in the financial market. The COVID-19 crisis has already mystified the relationship between these two key dollar funding rates – CP/CD and FX swap basis- in at least two ways. First, even though they should logically track each other tightly according to the arbitrage conditions, they diverged markedly during the pandemic episode. Second, an unusual anomaly had emerged in the FX swap markets, when the market signaled a US dollar premium and discount simultaneously.  For the scholars of Money View, these so-called anomalies are a legitimate child of the modern international monetary system where agents are disciplined, or rewarded, based on their position in the hierarchy. This hierarchy is created by the hand of God, aka the Fed, whose impact on nearly all financial assets and the money market, in particular, is so unmistakable. In this monetary system, a Darwinian inequality, which is determined by how close a country is to the sole issuer of the US dollar, the Fed, is an inherent quality of the system.

Most of these developments ultimately have their roots in dislocations in the banking system. At the heart of the issue is that a decade after the GFC, the private US Banks are still pulling back from supplying offshore dollar funding. Banks’ reluctance to lend has widened the LIBOR-OIS spread and made the Eurodollar market less attractive. Money market funds are filling the void and becoming the leading providers of dollar funding globally. Consequently, the CP/CD ratio, which measures the cost of borrowing from money market funds, has replaced a bank-centric, LIBOR-OIS spread and has become one of the primary indicators of offshore dollar funding costs.

The market for offshore dollar funding is also facing displacements on the demand side. International investors, including non-US banks, appear to utilize the FX swap market as the primary source of raising dollar funding. Traditionally, the bank-centric market for Eurodollar deposits was the one-stop-shop for these investors. Such a switch has made the FX swap basis, or “the basis,” another significant thermometer for calculating the cost of global dollar funding. This piece shows that this shift of reliance from banks to market-based finance to obtain dollar funding has created odd trends in the dollar funding costs.

Further, in the world of market-based finance, channeling dollars to non-banks is not straightforward as unlike banks, non-banks are not allowed to transact directly with the central bank. Even though the Fed started such a direct relationship through Money Market Mutual Fund Liquidity Facility or MMLF, the pandemic revealed that there are attendant difficulties, both in principle and in practice. Banks’ defiance to be stable providers of the dollar funding has created such irregularities in this market and difficulties for the central bankers.

The first peculiar trend in the global dollar funding is that the FX swap basis has continuously remained non-zero after the pandemic, defying the arbitrage condition. The FX swap basis is the difference between the dollar interest rate in the money market and the implied dollar interest rate from the FX swap market where someone borrows dollars by pledging another currency collateral. Arbitrage suggests that any differences between these two rates should be short-lived as there is always an arbitrageur, usually a carry trader, inclined to borrow from the market that offers a low rate and lend in the other market, where the rate is high. The carry trader will earn a nearly risk-free spread in the process. A negative (positive) basis means that borrowing dollars through FX swaps is more expensive (cheaper) than borrowing in the dollar money market.

Even so, the most significant irregularity in the FX swap markets had emerged when the market signaled a US dollar premium and a discount simultaneously.  The key to deciphering this complexity is to carefully examine the two interest rates that anchor FX swap pricing. The first component of the FX swap basis reflects the cost of raising dollar funding directly from the banks. In the international monetary system, not all banks are created equal. For the US banks who have direct access to the Fed’s liquidity facilities and a few other high-powered non-US banks, whose national central banks have swap lines with the Fed, the borrowing cost is close to a risk-free interest rate (OIS). At the same time, other non-US banks who do not have any access to the central bank’s dollar liquidity facilities should borrow from the unsecured Eurodollar market, and pay a higher rate, called LIBOR.

As a result, for corporations that do not have credit lines with the banks that are at the top of the hierarchy, borrowing from the banking system might be more expensive than the FX swap market. For these countries, the US dollar trades at a discount in the FX swap market. Contrarily, when banks finance their dollar lending activities at a risk-free rate, the OIS rate, borrowing from banks might be less more expensive for the firms. In this case, the US dollar trades at a premium in the FX swap market. To sum up, how connected, or disconnected, a country’s banking system is to the sole issuer of the dollar, i.e., the Fed, partially determines whether the US dollar funding is cheaper in the money market or the FX swap market.

The other crucial interest rate that anchors FX swap pricing and is at the heart of this anomaly in the FX swap market is the “implied US dollar interest rate in the FX swap market.”  This implied rate, as the name suggests, reflects the cost of obtaining dollar funding indirectly. In this case, the firms initially issue non-bank domestic money market instruments, such as commercial papers (CP) or certificates of deposits (CDs), to raise national currency and convert the proceeds to the US dollar. Commercial paper (CP) is a form of short-term unsecured debt commonly issued by banks and non-financial corporations and primarily held by prime money market funds (MMFs). Similarly, certificates of deposit (CDs) are unsecured debt instruments issued by banks and largely held by non-bank investors, including prime MMFs. Both instruments are important sources of funding for international firms, including non-US banks. The economic justification of this approach highly depends on the active presence of Money Market Funds (MMFs), and their ability and willingness, to purchase short-term money market instruments, such as CPs or CDs.

To elaborate on this point, let’s use an example. Let us assume that a Japanese firm wants to raise $750 million. The first strategy is to borrow dollars directly from a Japanese bank that has access to the global dollar funding market. Another competing strategy is to raise this money by issuing yen-denominated commercial paper, and then use those yens as collateral, and swap them for fixed-rate dollars of the same term. The latter approach is only economically viable if there are prime MMFs that are able and willing, to purchase that CP, or CD, that are issued by that firm, at a desirable rate. It also depends on FX swap dealers’ ability and willingness to use their balance sheet to find a party wanting to do the flip side of this swap. If for any reason these prime MMFs decide to withdraw from the CP or CD market, which has been the case after the COVID-19 crisis, then the cost of choosing this strategy to raise dollar funding is unequivocally high for this Japanese firm. This implies that the disruptions in the CP/CD markets, caused by the inability of the MMFs to be the major buyer in these markets, echo globally via the FX swap market.

On the other hand, if prime MMFs continue to supply liquidity by purchasing CPs, raising dollar funding indirectly via the FX swap market becomes an economically attractive solution for our Japanese firm. This is especially true when the regional banks cannot finance their offshore dollar lending activities at the OIS rate and ask for higher rates. In this case, rather than directly going to a bank, a borrower might raise national currency by issuing CP and swap the national currency into fixed-rate dollars in the FX swap market. Quite the contrary, if issuing short-term money market instruments in the domestic financial market is expensive, due to the withdrawal of MMFs from this market, for instance, the investors in that particular region might find the banking system the only viable option to obtain dollar funding even when the bank rates are high. For such countries, the high cost of bank-lending, and the shortage of bank-centric dollar funding, is an essential threat to the monetary stability of the firms, and the domestic monetary system as a whole.

After the COVID-19 crisis, it is like a tug of war emerged between OIS rates and the LIBORs as to which type of interest rate that anchor FX swap pricing. Following the pandemic, the LIBOR-OIS spread widened significantly and this war was intensified. Money View declares the winner, even before the war ends, to be the bankers, and non-bankers, who have direct, or at least secure path to the Fed’s balance sheet. Marcy Stigum, in her seminal book, made it clear not to fight the Fed and emphasized the powerful role of the Federal Reserve in the monetary system! Time and time again, investors have learned that it is fruitless to ignore the Fed’s powerful influence. Yet, some authors put little effort into trying to gain a better understanding of this powerful institution. They see the Fed as too complex, secretive, and mysterious to be readily understood. This list does not include Money View scholars. In the Money View framework, the US banks that have access to the Fed’s balance sheet are at the highest layer of the private banking hierarchy. Following them are a few non-US banks that have indirect access to the Fed’s swap lines through their national central bank. For the rest of the world, having access to the world reserve currency only depends on the mercy of the Gods.

Categories
Elham's Money View Blog

Can Shadow Banking Replace Traditional Banking? We Will See Soon Enough

By Elham Saeidinezhad

“A person often meets his destiny on the road he took to avoid it.” Jean De La Fontaine

The shift in the provision of financial intermediation away from traditional banks towards the shadow banking system highlights the evolving structure of the financial market. The recent disorder in the short-term repo market has created new openings for money managers. Money managers, such as money market funds and investment funds, are hoarding unusually large amounts of cash in anticipation of the excessive demand for liquidity on December 31st. In doing so, they are planning to serve both as the primary cash providers and the lender of near last resort in the repo market. Traditionally, the latter is the role that the large banks are inclined to have in the repo market. This shift in market structure from banking to shadow banking system seems to be the unintended consequence of the Fed’s tapering and regulatory requirements. It is also no accident that the change in the investment strategy of money managers coincides with the unwillingness of the large banks to borrow from the discount window of the Fed. This reluctance by banks cost the financial system the recent turmoil in the overnight lending market in September. The repo market experiment at the end of December, where money managers are preparing to take over the banks’ role, will be a real-world stress test of this new system.

In this piece, we focus on three factors that derive these changes in the market structure. These forces include Basel III regulatory requirements, Fed’s tapering, and the reluctance of banks to use the discount window to prevent the run on them. Post-crisis macroprudential requirements demand banks to keep a certain level of High-Quality Liquid Assets (HQLA) such as reserves. For example, JPMorgan Chase keeps about $120 billion in reserves at the Fed and will not let it dip below $60 billion on any given day. These requirements reduced banks’ ability to be intermediaries between the Fed and other players. Further, the Fed’s tapering that involved the reduction of the Fed asset purchases reduced the amounts of reserves in the banking system. These factors constrained banks’ ability to provide cash in the repo market during September turbulences. Meanwhile, although the amounts of reserves in the system have shrunk, banks are reluctant to use the Fed’s credit facilities, including the discount window. The Global Financial Crisis has only worsened the stigma attached to using the discount loan for at least two reasons: first, the Dodd-Frank requires the name of the banks that borrow from the discount window to be released. Second, banks are worried that borrowing money from the Fed spur a run on these institutions.

Soon, the resilience of the most critical market for short-term borrowing will be tested when stress hits the system under a new condition. In this unique situation, when there is excessive demand for the cash, both the primary provider of funding liquidity and the lender of near last resort will be shadow banking system, who does not have the Fed’s backstop, rather than the large banks, who do. Perry Mehrling defines shadow banking as the money market funding of capital market lending. In this system, money market funds are primary providers of the funding liquidity. These funds are plotting to seize the new opportunity of becoming the lender of near last resort in December mostly because the large banks did not intervene when the repo rates hiked in September. The main question that remains to be answered is whether this new system will survive extensive pressure. After all, the bolstered role of shadow banking in the repo market is an unintended, rather than planned, consequences of post-crisis macroeconomic and regulatory changes.

Discussion Questions:

  1. Which regulatory requirements have constrained the ability of the banks to lend to the repo market?
  2. What does the lender of near last resort mean?
  3. Who are the main players in the shadow banking system?